The challenges central banks have been facing over the past two decades, are to some extent comparable. The period of macroeconomic stability and financial boom that marked the first years of this century was followed by the Global Financial Crisis, a deep recession and a serious risk of deflation. In recent years, we have witnessed major supply side shocks, such as the Covid pandemic and the war in Ukraine, which triggered an energy crisis. This drove up global inflation to double-digit levels. Like in the 1920s, we are also witnessing heightened uncertainty and geopolitical tensions, an increasing backlash against globalisation and a growing support for inward-looking policies in many parts of the world. As a result, globalisation has come to a halt, as you can see in the graphs. Very expansionary monetary policies in the decade after the Global Financial Crisis led to ballooning central bank balance sheets. When inflation and interest rates rose sharply in recent years, central banks made significant losses, as they did in the 1930s.
But in some respects the current period is different from the interwar years. In particular, the fiscal, monetary and regulatory responses to the Great Financial Crisis have avoided a repeat of the Great Depression. Fiscal policy has been used to absorb the costs of the near collapse of the banking system and to respond to the sharp fall in output. Monetary authorities have used conventional and unconventional tools to support macroeconomic stability.
After the double shock of the Covid pandemic and Russia’s invasion of Ukraine, major central banks managed to tame inflation by responding forcefully. Key to this success is that – unlike in the 1970s and 1980s – inflation expectations remained well-anchored. This reflects the credibility of monetary authorities in their pursuit of price stability. I will come back to this later in my talk.
And, following a period of financial liberalisation between the 1980s and the global financial crisis, prudential policy has been used to strengthen the resilience of the financial sector and to mitigate excessive swings in the financial cycle.
Looking forward, new developments have emerged, notably structural changes in the economy as a result of ageing populations, the climate transition, and the digital revolution. These pose challenges to central banks in their pursuit of price stability. And, as I mentioned, central banks need to be independent to meet these challenges effectively, as well as for other good reasons.
So let me now delve a bit deeper into the arguments for central bank independence. Central bank independence did not come about overnight. In fact, with his advice that the new Turkish central bank should be independent, Gerard Vissering was ahead of his time. In the early 1900s, there were just 18 central banks in the world. They often lacked a clear legal or autonomous status to set monetary and financial policies. They functioned primarily as the executive arm of the government.
The concept of central bank independence only truly matured in the final two decades of the 20th century. The main macroeconomic challenge of the 1980s was to deal with the so-called Great Inflation that marked the 1970s and early 1980s. Questions arose such as why inflation was so tenacious and how monetary policy contributed to its endurance.
A new macroeconomic paradigm emerged during this period, which emphasised the importance of time-consistent policies and credibility for macroeconomic stability. Proponents of this view highlighted the government's inclination to inflate the economy, particularly prior to elections, thus creating an inflationary bias. To counteract this tendency towards excessive inflation, an institutional mechanism was needed to limit government interference in monetary policy. Seminal work by Kenneth Rogoff (1985) proposed a solution through which monetary policy would be entrusted to a conservative central bank with a strong mandate against inflation, and free from government influence. As a result, central bank independence emerged as a safeguard against a recurrence of the high inflation of the 1970s.
The advantages of this approach extend further. If inflation expectations were stable, monetary policy could be used effectively to stabilise economic output. Consequently, central bank independence appeared to offer dual benefits: a reduction in inflation without an increase in output variability. As the 1980s and 1990s unfolded, with more central banks gaining operational autonomy, empirical studies increasingly confirmed that central bank independence played a significant role in diminishing inflation rates. This body of evidence then supported the momentum toward greater central bank independence in the later years of the 20th century.
But still, it took time and effort in many countries to wrest the mighty instrument of money from the clutches of government. In the UK, famously, the Bank of England only gained policy independence in 1998. Also in my country, the process did not go smoothly. Let me tell you what happened in 1983, for example. Back then, the Netherlands was participating in the European Exchange Rate Mechanism, and the Minister of Finance was responsible for setting the parity of the domestic currency. For years, DNB’s monetary strategy had been based on firmly pegging the Dutch guilder to the German mark. By doing so, we had successfully imported the credibility of the Bundesbank, which was at that time the champion of monetary orthodoxy. When, in 1983, the Deutschmark revalued against the other western-European currencies, the Dutch government, for reasons of competitiveness, and against the advice of the Dutch central bank, did not fully follow the German move. That proved to be a costly decision, particularly for the highly indebted Dutch government. As a result of this breach of a long standing policy commitment, Dutch interest rates rose vis-à-vis German interest rates, reflecting a visible risk premium. It took about 10 years for this interest rate differential to come down.
The arrival of the Economic and Monetary Union was an important step for central bank independence in Western Europe. Germany, with my country’s support, insisted that the Bundesbank model of firm central bank independence would be copied to the newly established European Central Bank. The Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union provides that the ECB “shall be independent in the exercise of its powers”. Importantly, this independence also applies to the EU's national central banks. This ensures that no single EU Member State can change or revoke the ECB’s independence alone.
Standing on this firm legal footing, I think that overall the ECB has been successful in establishing its reputation as an independent and firmly committed inflation fighter. As you know, this has not come without challenges. The Great Financial Crisis, followed by the euro sovereign debt crisis and the Covid pandemic, spurred the ECB, together with other central banks, to resort to unconventional policies. This involved purchasing huge amounts of government bonds, which for some critics blurred the distinction between monetary and fiscal policy and raised questions about central bank independence.
Without going into that discussion at length, I think this episode did not tarnish the ECB’s reputation for being tough on inflation. Examining the behaviour of inflation expectations can be quite insightful here. They serve as a critical measure of how credible a monetary regime remains over time. When the regime is trusted, these expectations should remain stable around the target and not be significantly influenced by short-term economic changes.
A real test of the ECB’s credibility came when the two shocks of the Covid pandemic and Russia’s invasion of Ukraine sent inflation rates soaring to levels not seen since the 1970s. When inflation pressures started to mount in the course of 2021 following a prolonged period of below-target inflation, my colleagues and I on the Governing Council decided to wait with tightening our policy until sufficient evidence was available to suggest that the large inflation shocks were not just temporary. Once a second inflation shock hit in the spring of 2022, with Russia’s invasion of Ukraine, it became evident that inflation pressures were becoming persistent. Although that meant we started tightening policy a little bit later than we could have, our forceful response prevented high inflation from causing a de-anchoring of inflation expectations.